Gary
Becker, a Nobel laureate economist, analyzed marriage, births, divorce,
division of labor in households, inequality, altruism and other nonmaterial
behavior with the tools and framework developed for material behavior, i.e.
economics. His purpose was to develop a rational choice approach to the family.
In his book, “A Treatise on the Family”, Becker used basic tools of economics
and derived conclusions, some of which may sound counter-intuitive.
Division of labor
Becker
analyzes division of household labor in chapter 2 of the book. He argues that
even if a husband and wife are intrinsically identical, they gain from a
division of labor between market and household activities, with one of them
specializing more in market activities and the other specializing more in
household activities. What he introduced to derive the conclusion is the
concept of relative advantage and human capital investment. The followings are
the theorems in chapter 2 (page 33 to 36):
Theorem
2.1. If all
members of an efficient household have different comparative advantages, no more
than one member would allocate time to both the market and household sectors.
Everyone with a greater comparative advantage in the market than this member’s
would specialize completely in the market, and everyone with a greater
comparative advantage in the household would specialize completely there.
Theorem
2.2. If all
members of a household have different comparative advantages, no more than one
member would invest in both market and household capital. Members specializing
in the market sector would invest only in market capital, and members
specializing in the household sector would invest only in household capital.
Theorem
2.3. At most
one member of an efficient household would invest in both market and household
capital and would allocate time to both sectors.
Theorem
2.4. If
commodity production functions have constant or increasing returns to scale,
all members of efficient households would specialize complete in the market or
household sectors and would invest only in market or household capital.
These
theorems would explain the fact that in many families, there is division of
labor to some extent, and in some cases those who spend time for market labor
also do for household labor as well. Becker’s statement also shows us that why
the labor division is made based on sexual differences – it is because only a
slight difference leads to division of labor and once the division is made, the
comparative advantages of family members would get fixed. Note, however, that
Becker did not say that biological difference is the sole reason of labor
division, or “exploitation of household women”.
Becker
also mentions about the recent trends in women’s labor force participation
rates, fertility, and divorce rates. The rapid expansion of the service sector
enabled more women to participate into market labors. Thus, “the growth in the
earning power of married women raised the forgone value of their time spent at
child care and other household activities, which in turn reduced the demand for
children and encouraged a substitution away from parental, especially mothers’
time. Both of these changes raised the labor force participation of married
women. The gain from marriage is reduced, and hence the attractiveness of
divorce is raised, by higher earnings and labor force participation of married
women, because the sexual division of labor within household becomes less
advantageous.” (page 55) The same can be
said for the women in the course of economic independence in developing
countries.
Competition in marriage market
Chapter
3 and 4 analyze the competition for marriage partners among men and women of
different incomes, abilities, education ages, family backgrounds, and other
attributes.
An
efficient marriage market develops “shadow” prices to guide participants to
marriages that will maximize their expected well-being. These prices, central
to the analysis in this chapter and the subsequent one, are responsible for the
more powerful implications.
The
general concept of marriage in Becker’s model is that marriage increases output
of both male and female, and the marginal increase of output from an additional
husband/wife is positive. In this setup, polygamy is more beneficial for both
male and female, if either men or women differ significantly in efficiency
(ability to generate output), or if the ratio of eligible men to eligible men
and eligible women differ significantly, the conclusion that is analogous to
the efficient use of resources.
Becker’s
model explains under what situation people would invest more in superior skill
(the skill that makes one attractive), e.g. having education, training, etc.
Becker argues that, when the marginal contribution of women/men to output is
greater, people have more incentive to invest to increase their efficiency.
Usually, polygamy increases the expected marginal increase of output, as
men/women can choose more than one mate.
This
model suggests explanation of why polygyny is more common than polyandry. The
situation originally begins with a small difference. If the marginal
contribution of women is larger, that incentivizes men to invest more in their
skills and women to invest less (as they have more expected opportunity to get
married), and that raises the average efficiency and the inequality in
efficiency of men relative to women. The difference of contribution for output
may be coming from biological difference. Becker said that both average and
standard deviation of years of schooling are usually much lower for women than
men in poor countries with monogamous marriages, where presumably the marginal
contribution of women to output is greater than the marginal contribution of
men because of the value of having many children. (page 104)
Becker
then analyzes assortative mating using the same framework. He says that correlations
between intelligence, education, age, race, nonhuman wealth, religion, ethnic
origin, height, place of origin, and many other traits of spouses are positive
and strong. Especially the correlation between spouses by intelligence is
strong – it is as high as that between siblings. On the other hand, persons who
marry out of their race, religion, age cohort, or education class have
relatively high probabilities of divorce, even when other traits are held constant.
(page 117-118)
Becker
argues that preferences could well affect the equilibrium sorting if costs were
no the same in all households. For example, persons with similar preferences
have an incentive to marry each other if costs are lower when the consumption
patterns of mates are more similar, as they would be when some commodities are
jointly consumed, when production of commodities is more efficient at a larger
scale, or when specialized consumption capital lowers the costs of particular
commodities. (page 123)
Love
can also be understood in Becker’s framework. Love can be defined such that
her/his welfare enters his/her utility function or that he/she values emotional
and physical contact with her/him.
The demand for children
Becker
applied the same economic framework to fertility.
One
factor deeply affecting child birth rate is children’s future productivity. In
the past, there was more child birth in suburban area, because having more
children was more productive on farms than in cities. The reason is that
agriculture in the past did not require any complex labor, and thus children at
young age can contribute to enhance a family’s productivity. The contribution
of farm children has declined as agriculture has become more mechanized and
complex in the course of economic development.
Second
factor is the value of the time of married women, because the cost of the
mother’s time is a major part of the total cost of producing and rearing
children. The number of children is strongly negatively related to the wage
rate or other measures of the value of time of wives. Becker said that the
growth in the earning power of women during the last hundred years in developed
countries is a major cause of both the large increase in labor force
participation of married women and the large decline in fertility. (page 140)
Third
factor is education and the number of children. There are negative correlation
between the number of children and the quality of education for them (see the
table below). Becker points out that Jewish families have been smaller than
average over the last 150 years and have invested more in human capital, and in
recent decades they have had higher incomes.
Country
and period
|
Change
in
birth
rate
|
Change
in schooling
|
US
1920 -1930
|
-24%
|
+81%
|
US
1960 – 1972
|
-38%
|
+33%
|
Japan
1950-1960
|
-45%
|
+37%
|
Taiwan
1960 – 1975
|
-51%
|
+100%
|
England
& Wales 1871-1901
|
-26%
|
+21%
|
Becker also points out that government programs significantly
affected child birth rate. The recent increase in fertility rate in France
would be a good example to show that families would respond to the monetary
incentives in deciding the number of children.
Inequality and Intergenerational Mobility
Becker
also analyzes inequality. He argues that even if all families were basically
identical, incomes would be unequally distributed because of the unequal
incidence of endowment and market luck. The inequality prevails over
generations, as lucky parents invest more in their children, and the increase
in the children’s incomes would induce them to invest more in their own
children in the succeeding generation, and soon until all descendants benefit
from the initial luck (page 203). Moreover, Children’s incomes are linked to
their parents not only through investments but also through such endowments as
reputation, connections, knowledge, skills, goals provided by their family
environment, genetically determined race and other characteristics.
Altruism
Becker’s
argument about intergenerational mobility assumes that parents feel better if
their children are better off, i.e. the utility function of parents are made of
both their own income and the quality of children. Becker analyzes the altruism
in the family in this book as well. According to Becker, “altruistic” means
that one’s utility function depends positively on the well-being of others.
Say an
altruist is the mother of a family and has several beneficiaries, including
children, spouses, parents and siblings. Becker analyzes the situation more
profoundly and proposes an interesting theorem (page 288):
Rotten Kid Theorem: Each beneficiary, no matter how
selfish, maximizes the family income of his benefactor and thereby internalizes
all effects of his actions on other beneficiaries.
Corollary: Each beneficiary, no matter how envious
of other beneficiaries or of his benefactor, maximizes the family income of the
benefactor, and hence helps those envied.
Remarks
It is
surprising to see that the economic model of this book well describes the
behavior of family to the large extent. Human beings may not be rational as an
individual but may be very rational as a group, and frameworks of economics are
very powerful tool to analyze the situation (sometimes they reveal
uncomfortable truth though). That is why I believe to learn economics is
valuable for everyone even for those who don’t care about economy.
Reference
Gary
Becker, “A Treatise on the Family”, Harvard University Press (Enlarged edition),
1993/10/15
No comments:
Post a Comment